A fertility rate of 2.1 per woman is the minimum needed to stabilise a
society's population. Anything below that will cause population to
decline within a generation. Europe is at 1.55, Japan is at 1.3 and most
of the important countries of Europe are around 1.3. Germany, Italy and
Russia are at the bottom of the heap. Even China is at 1.6. More
importantly, there is no historic precedent for a country to increase a
declining birth rate except through immigration. The US is doing that,
raising its birth rate for white Caucasians from 1.9 to a national birth
rate of 2.1, just enough to maintain population. The difference is made
up by the higher fertility of African- Americans and Hispanics.
Why does this happen? In low-income
societies, children are seen as an earning asset and a support system in
old age. In developed societies, children are a drain on parental
resources, and increasingly, not much of a support in old age. We have
seen this spectacularly in urban India which has moved from the joint
family system to nuclear and even individual family units in a single
generation. There is a direct correlation between urbanisation, per
capita GDP and a drop in fertility rates.
Throughout my
generation, we have rued a high population growth and celebrated low
(population) growth rates. But the deflation/depression that pervades
societies in long-term demographic decline is visible in Japan for the
last 25 years and is now being anticipated in almost the entire
developed world. It creates an 'inverted pyramid', where a small number
of workers have to support a large number of dependents. This increasing
dependence ratio creates stresses in society, especially when the
government debt (and social obligations) of earlier generations has to
be paid off. That is why the current deflation/depression scenario could
prove to be especially burdensome on the coming generation.
At
an individual (country) level, immigration and productivity growth could
mitigate the effect of the debt hangover. Japan has seen very high
productivity growth in a deflationary economy, which is why at an
individual level we have not seen the kind of misery that one would
expect, say, in a depression. The per capital GDP has stayed buoyant, in
a zero-inflation economy, leading to better living standards despite a
high dependence ratio. High savings and a persistent current account
surplus have ensured that Japan remains a creditor nation. In a perverse
way, the new Abenomics philosophy to print money and service debt will
eventually lead to inflation, but if it happens after the ageing 65+
segment has been seen off, there will be much less misery than if they
had taken any other course. Once the 'geriatric hump' has been seen off,
a sharp inflationary shock that demonetises the Yen and reissues a new
currency would settle the bankruptcy problem once and for all. This has
been done before (in Germany in 1920). In a country with a low
dependency ratio, wages will catch up with inflation, provided
productivity remains buoyant. Higher productivity produces a
higher stock of capital, especially over a longer period of time. As
population drops and debt gets paid off, a society gets richer in real
terms, not poorer. Throughout history, population has been rising and so
has debt, resulting in lower equity per person (aka wealth). Now, as
the equation reverses, a dropping absolute number of people with a
rising cumulative stock of capital (i.e., wealth) will result in higher
equity per person. This will reduce leverage ratios and lead to higher
consumption, which is a must if all that higher productivity is to find
an outlet. For the first time in history, higher wealth will come with a
falling population. That will make labour more scarce than capital, and
I don't know how society will handle that. Certainly, the elitist
mindsets that wear the suits in finance and industry today would be
caught unprepared, I am sure. Politicians also will be blindsided. All
this will take a good half-century to play out but will be seen at
different stages in different societies. India will have time to learn
from others because it will be the last to enter this stage.
There
are two jokers in this pack. One, productivity rises so fast that it
renders labour surplus faster than the population can reduce. The magic
number is 2.5 per cent because the decline in most country populations
will be about 1 per cent in the worst of cases. This does not look
impossible, given the twin booms in energy and robotic automation that
seem to be round the corner. Two, they find breakthroughs in cloning or
some method of asexual reproduction, which allow specific countries or
ethnic groups to reverse their declining demography. At the moment, it
looks like Japan and Germany will do something drastic to arrest their
demographic decline.
Of the four inputs to production - land,
labour, organisation and capital - only two would be left valuable. In a
zero-cost energy society, also facing declining population, the real
cost of land would drop to nothing. We can see that spectacularly in
Japan, where real estate is still 80 per cent below 1989 levels. That
should be a lesson to those readers who look to real estate as the most
durable legacy they want to leave behind for the next generation.
Organisation
is just a higher form of labour, which in a falling population would
tip the scales in its favour, vis-á-vis capital. This would increase
the per capita GDP. Intelligent readers can draw some serious long-term
direction from this if they want to draw conclusions for planning their
children's careers. If I know crowds well, most people will be caught in
the middle of a real estate crisis before they start to question the
existing wisdom of 'real estate being the safest investment'. Bond
market bears who are perpetually betting on a sharp rise in interest
rates may find themselves waiting for Godot.
That brings us to
our final conclusion. With demographic decline, you get a falling cost
of capital, as opposed to the cost of labour. That reduces the
opportunity cost for investors, even as it reduces corporate
profitability because of wage inflation. So countries in demographic
decline, which include Japan, most of Europe, even China, are going to
see this scenario. These countries will also see rising wealth and
savings, even as they see falling investment opportunities. This is
already visible in some countries and will become visible in others (for
example, China).
Countries that are laggards in this
(demographic) trend, like the US and, of course, India, will have a
higher cost of capital and lower wage costs. They will see better
investment opportunities and, of course, will be net capital importers.
From a currency standpoint, it makes sense to 'carry trade' from poor
demography countries and invest into better demographies. We know that
carry trades work but only over the long-term. This would be
particularly true over periods of sharp demographic change like the ones
we are going to see over the next 15 years.
For Indian
investors, who are heavily loaded up with real estate, the path forward
is clear. A worldwide drop in the cost of capital will see
disinflationary trends drop the cost of capital, although we will not
step into deflation. This will reduce returns from real estate. They
would do well to borrow in currencies that are facing demographic
decline and find pockets in Indian markets, where you get healthy
differential returns. The actual methods may look a little complex
because they may have many legs, but the underlying philosophy is
recounted above. Remember one very important principle of investing: Go
where you can see predictability. Any investment hypothesis that is
based on something as unchangeable as demographics has to be very
robust. And this single hypothesis could help you generate outsize
returns for a very long time in the future.
No comments:
Post a Comment